Capital quality and the illiquidity
premium - The current debate on the illiquidity premium
[this page | pdf | references | back links]
Article by Malcolm Kemp – 27
May 2010
Copyright (c) Malcolm Kemp 2010
Return to
Abstract and Contents
Next
Section
1. The current
debate on the illiquidity premium
The background to the meteoric rise in the perceived
importance (to actuaries) of the illiquidity premium may be summarised as
follows:
-
Some insurers have material exposures to illiquid liabilities,
particularly in annuity books. Annuity policies are typically considered to be
highly illiquid and relatively long-term, because they cannot normally be
cancelled. Many such insurers have ‘matched’ this illiquidity in their
liabilities by investing in correspondingly illiquid assets, e.g. illiquid
corporate bonds generating similar cash flow payment profiles to those required
to meet the annuity liabilities as they fall due.
-
These insurers have often also adjusted downwards the values they have
placed on these liabilities, to reflect the perceived illiquidity yield premium
available from investing in these assets. When commentators refer to the
‘illiquidity premium’ they are generally referring to the part of the overall
yield spread (versus liquid highly rated government bonds) that is not
perceived by the commentator to be merely a ‘fair’ compensation for the extra
credit (i.e. default) risk carried by corporate bonds (or for the uncertainty
in the future magnitude of this risk) but reflects differences in the current
(and future) liquidity exhibited by these instruments.
-
Insurers have adjusted valuations of illiquid liabilities in this type
of fashion not just in solvency valuations but also when pricing annuity
policies, including bulk annuity purchases that pension funds might wish to
make.
-
Even small differences in annualised yield spreads can compound to large
differences in liability valuations. At the height of the recent credit crisis
some commentators estimated the magnitude of the liquidity premium as in excess
of 2% pa. This might equate to, say, a c. 20 – 30% change in value for an
illiquid liability with a c. 10 to 15 year average duration. The impact of the
illiquidity premium can be substantial both for sellers of such policies
(insurers) and for buyers (pension funds as well as individuals).
-
Although the recent financial crisis is most commonly referred to as a credit
crisis, it could arguably be better described as a liquidity crisis. The
banks that failed were disproportionately ones that relied on the wholesale
markets for their funding. It was when these funding sources dried up that they
ran into problems, because they were then unable to source the liquidity they
needed to continue as going concerns.
-
As a result, regulators have become much more focused on liquidity risk.
This applies not just to banking regulators. Last autumn, EU insurance
regulators (CEIOPS) preparing for Solvency II proposed that for regulatory
capital purposes EU insurers should value annuity liabilities by discounting at
a ‘risk-free’ discount rate derived from highly rated government bonds, i.e. without
including an illiquidity yield premium.
-
Predictably, some insurers with large annuity books lobbied hard to have
this stance reversed, claiming that it might require an extra £50bn of capital
and lead to reductions in annuities to pensioners by between 10 and 20 per cent
according to e.g. The Times (2009).
The Association of British Insurers went on record as arguing that the proposed
use of a yield curve derived from ‘AAA’ Government bonds would “cause
massive disruption in the capital markets and a huge artificial inflation in
the value of liabilities. A ‘liquidity premium’ should be recognised and taken
into account in the risk free rate, in particular for long term non redeemable
liabilities”. CEIOPS’s original stance has also been referred to by some as
‘reckless prudence’.
-
CEIOPS responded by commissioning a Task Force on the Illiquidity
Premium, which reported in March 2010, see CEIOPS (2010).
Its members were split about whether there was a sound theoretical basis for
incorporating an illiquidity premium in the discount rates used to value
illiquid long-term liabilities, and, to the extent that there was one, on how
practical it might be to estimate its size reliably. This lack of consensus is
perhaps not surprising. Kemp (2009)
highlights that there are several different possible economic interpretations
for liquidity risk. Some support the use of an illiquidity premium in this way
whilst others do not. However, the Task Force did propose a pragmatic way
forward, to the extent that it was felt appropriate to include an illiquidity
premium at all, which involved deeming some proportion of the total yield spread
available on corporate versus government bonds to correspond to an illiquidity
premium.
-
The Task Force report was included in the Level 2 advice on Solvency II
provided by CEIOPS to the EU Commission. The EU Commission subsequently
indicated in the draft technical specifications for the Solvency II
Quantitative Impact Study 5 that it was minded to allow inclusion of an
illiquidity premium. The draft technical specifications included two sets of
yield curves applicable as at 31 December 2009, one deemed to exclude the
illiquidity premium and one deemed to include it. For liabilities with average
durations of c. 10 to 15 years, the difference between them corresponded to a
c. 5 to 10% difference in value, depending on the currency in question.
NAVIGATION LINKS
Contents | Prev | Next